Studying the Effect of Economic, Social and Organizational Factors on Organizational Justice in the Educational Research and Planning Organization
Subject Areas : International Journal of Finance, Accounting and Economics StudiesErshad Estedadi 1 , mehrdad Godarzvand chegini 2 , Heidar Toorani 3
1 - PhD student, Department of Public Administration, Faculty of Management and Economics, Science and Research Unit, Islamic Azad University, Tehran, Iran
2 - Faculty of Islamic Azad University, Rasht, Iran.
3 - Academic staff of Research Institute of Education Studies, Tehran, Iran
Keywords: Organizational justice, organizational cohesion, Organizational Behavior, research organization and educational planning,
Abstract :
The aim and topic of the research: The aim of the present study is to design and present the model of organizational justice based on the variables of economic, social, and organizational factors.Research method: This research is one of the types of applied research in terms of its purpose and mixed research in terms of its approach. The statistical population is the experts and specialists in the field of management and organizational behavior and the employees of the research and educational planning organization. The method of sampling experts (qualitative part of research), snowball method, and sampling method of employees (quantitative part of research) was random. 12 people were selected in the qualitative section and 187 people were selected in the quantitative section. The tool was the qualitative part of the interview and the quantitative part of the questionnaire.Findings: Economic, social and organizational factors have a positive and significant effect on organizational justice. Based on the qualitative results, it was determined that 134 concepts were extracted from scientific studies and the analysis of the themes of interviews with experts and specialists, focusing on the concepts related to the research topic.
Developing the Capital Asset Pricing Model Using the Noise Based Behavioral Model (N-CAPM)
Mehdi Barasoud1, Gholam Reza Zomorodian21, Fereydon Rahnama Roodposhti3
1 Ph.D. Student in Finance, Department of Financial Engineering, Science and Research Branch, Islamic Azad University, Tehran, Iran. 2* Professor, Department of Business Administration, Tehran Center Branch, Islamic Azad University, Tehran, Iran. 3 Professor and Faculty Member Department of Management and Accounting, Science and Research Branch, Islamic Azad University, Tehran, Iran. |
|
|
[1] Corresponding Author: gh.zomorodian@gmail.com.
©2023, Tehran Center Branch, Islamic Azad University, Tehran, Iran.All right reserved
Article History | Abstract |
Submission Date: 22 February 2022 Revised Date: 10 March 2022 Accepted Date: 07 May 2022 Available Online: 20 July 2022 | In this study, we aim to show the effects of noise in the process of stock valuation and a new behavioral analysis model of noise-based capital asset pricing (N-CAPM) or human judgments was presented to assess the effects of the judgments on decision makings. Using five experts’ opinions of capital market, who had not been related to each other, the stock valuation of five selected corporations was defined. In this direction, we have used the Dividend Discount Model (DDM), Free Cash Flow to Equity (FCFE), and Price-Earnings ratio (P/E), for the period of 2024-2026. We found out that considering noise in the process of stock valuation decreases the fluctuations or risks of stocks compared with other market stocks and can produce less inflammation and fluctuation in values. Therefore, not considering the noise level can cause asset price deviation, make it unreal, and more increase the prices. Of course, because of time-consuming valuation process of corporations, we had some limitations to use many other experts’ views. Then we suggest that the next researchers, rather than three methods, choose one and an industry, for example automobile, to reduce the limitations and achieve the better results. Also, we hope that they would analyze the human factors such as individual’s personality, view, and past experiences which affect decision making as well as the variables like stock turnover, general knowledge, and technical analysis on stock valuation. Understanding more deeply the market noise, managers can professionally manage the sudden evolutions and unexpected risks.
|
JEL Classification: | |
Keyword: The Capital Asset Pricing Model Noise Stock valuation |
1. Introduction
Every day, a large number of securities are priced according to interaction of various variables each of them differently affect the prices. In many studies, the patterns or mechanisms of this market are examined. In financial economics texts, risk and return are two main factors for decision making on an investment. An individual decision, in this market, is based on choosing the high profitable and low risk assets. Assessing their sensitivity on the risk and return of an asset, investors have to choose their best portfolios. Basically, the researchers of financial economics have focused on considering the risk factor, relation between expected risk and return, and offering a model to show this connection. Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) is one of the most important models for showing correlation of expected risk and return. Many theories of the modern financial economics are based on this classic model. CAPM explains the relation between anticipated risk and return. There is a balance between anticipated risk and return in the center of this model. These models, essentially, are used to access a portfolio (Zarifhonarvar, 2023). Over time, it was recognized that the model cannot sometimes measure well the relation between risk and return (Bodie et al, 2013; Zarifhonarvar, 2023). For example, Basso’s study (1977) has showed that the stocks with high proportion of profit to price have more returns than the stocks with low proportion of profit to price. Or for instance, Adler (1981) has shown that the average stock returns of companies with low market value, was more than the stocks of companies with high market value. Therefore, it seems that defining factors other than stock price affect stock return. Hence, many efforts were made to improve fundamental models based on the different viewpoints about risk and return, including the models such as D-CAPM, C-CAPM, X-CAPM, etc. All data are considered in current prices according to the Efficient-Market Hypothesis; and any deviation of these changes affects rapidly on the prices. However, many exceptions of the relation between profit and return in financial markets have caused violation of Efficient-Market Hypothesis. These violations have led to create new theories in financial markets such as perspective theory by Daniel Kahneman and Rosenfield in 2016. These theories and many other events like financial crisis in markets have resulted in offering the behavioral-financial paradigm. Based on this paradigm, many economic and rational indicators, which are essential assumptions in traditional pricing models, have been violated in real world. Rejecting the many assumptions of classic theories, behavioral-financial paradigm, using some personal and behavioral features of investors, try to explain many events in financial markets. So far, a large number of researches are done to identify the kinds of financial biases, using personal and behavioral characteristics of investors. One of the newest asset pricing models based on behavioral patterns is X-CAPM (Barberis, 2013) which aim to price assets in accordance with behavioral patterns. On the other hand, when it comes to human judgment, a footprint of the noise theory can be found that is a theory on behavioral science, which explains the variation resulted from error. In other words, noise points to the difference between price and true value of stocks because of human decisions and factors. These factors can include psychological effects, fear and greed, the impacts resulted from behavioral deviations and news. Noise can cause unconformity between price and true value of stocks and lead to unfair and discontinuous changes in financial markets. For example, the level of experts’ knowledge and the price effects of the past can increase the noise in financial markets. It can lead to considerable changes of stock prices of companies and their unfair valuation. Noise can unbalance financial markets and create discontinuous and unexpected changes of stock prices. This kind of difference in human judgments can result in producing the profitable opportunities for professional investors or unexpected risks for common investors. Generally, noise can negatively influence financial markets, because unfair stock valuation can lead to price inflation, stock price imbalance, decreased confidence of investors, and other significant effects on the investors’ decisions. Accordingly, it is obvious that, to improve human judgments, the noises of individual thinking system must be recognized. Then, considering the current research gap around the human judgment role in stock valuation of companies in this market, this study has aimed to expand capital asset pricing model (CAPM), using the human judgment approach, and a new model is provided for noise-based capital asset pricing model (N-CAPM).
2. Literature Review
After presenting CAPM, many experimental and theoretical researches are conducted on the original model and its expansion. Several articles have been published about financial economics on this model, as both theoretical and experimental. Following the simple Sharp-Lintner model published in 1964-1965, some expanded models are suggested. Table 1 shows a complete list of models related to CAPM.
Table 1- Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) and its expanded models
Model | Author/Authors |
---|---|
Mean-Variance algorithm | Markowitz (1952) |
Sharpe-Lintner CAPM | Sharp (1964); Lintner (1965); Mossin (1966) |
Black Zero-beta CAPM | Black et al. (1972) |
CAPM with Human Capital | Mayers (1973) |
CAPM with Consumption Goods | Breeden (1979) |
International CAPM | Solnik (1974); Adler & Domas (1983) |
Arbitrage Pricing Theory | Ross (1976) |
Three factor model | Fama & French (1993) |
Partial Variance Approach | Hogan & Warren (1974); Bawa & Lindenberg (1977; Harlow & Rao (1989) |
The Three Moment CAPM | Rubinstein (1973); Kraus & Litzenberger (1976) |
The Four Moment CAPM | Fang & Lai (1997) |
The Intertemporal CAPM | Merton (1973) |
The Consumption CAPM | Breeden (1979) |
Production Based CAPM | Lucas (1978); Brock (1982) |
Investment-Based CAPM | Cochrane (1991) |
Liquidity Based CAPM | Acharya & Pedersen (2005) |
Conditional CAPM | Jagannathan & Wang (1996) |
Primary studies, on Sharp-Lintner model, has predicted the correlation between anticipated return and market beta. The problem of such researches was that incorrect estimates of beta for assets produced error of measurement. In addition, regression residual is considered as the source of variations. Researchers have suggested different methods to solve this problem. For example, Black et al. (1972) used stock securities. Beta for these incongruous portfolios was more accurate. Then, Fama and Makbeth (1973) asserted that, instead of a cross-sectional regression of average monthly return and beta, a monthly cross-sectional regression of monthly return over beta is necessary, that would decrease the problem of residual correlation.
Another approach first offered by Jensen (1968) who argued that the Sharp-Lintner model to explain the relation between anticipated return and beta can be tested by the time series methods.
Experimental studies are done in different countries such as Turkey, the United States of America, Finland, Sweden, Uganda, India, Italy, and Greek to investigate the gap between offered theories and real evidences. These studies have shown that the simple CAPM model cannot explain the relation between risk and return. Then, researchers such as Fama and French (1993) argued that experimental studies around this model had to be done more. Although the problems related to experimental researches can be resulted from the weakness of this model, from a theoretical point of view, the problems can also be resulted from lack of applied studies and reliable tests on the model.
In general, this model has many opponents as well as supporters. Some, like McGoun (1993), consider it as a huge failure, while others, like Levy (2010), argue that this approach is still reliable and practical. However, most researchers believe that adequacy of this model depends on when and in what circumstances it is used for decision making.
Due to wide usage of CAPM in financial researches, this model is considered as a standard one in theoretical and experimental literatures. This model was developed to explain the relation between risk of stock market and return. CAPM base on theoretical studies of Markovitz (1952) such as modern portfolio theory, mean-variance, and diversification was separately explained by Sharp (1964). From Mossin (1966) point of view according this model, risk of an asset is defined based on its return dependency to market portfolio return and the relation between anticipated return and risk is leaner and direct. Thus, CAPM is represented by Sharp and Lintner, using stock beta in 1960, as the following equation:
(1)
In which E(Ri) is anticipated return, RF is the return of security with no risk, and RM is the return of all market investment. This model divides the risk up into systematic and unsystematic. Systematic risk or beta (i) is how a stock acts in relation to market stocks, as which the anticipated return is depended on. However, unsystematic risk is related to special condition of any stock (Bodie et al., 2013).
Although this model at first was paid attention by investors to explain the relation between risk and return, it was over time addressed that the model sometimes cannot measure well the relation between risk and return. For instance, the research by Basso (19770 has shown that the stocks with high proportion of profit to price gain more returns than the stocks with low proportion of profit to price. Or for instance, Benz (1981) has shown that the stocks of companies with low market values have average return higher than the stocks of companies with high market values; therefore, it seems that determining factors other than stock prices affect stock returns. So, many efforts to improve fundamental models are made according to a different view to risk and return, including the models C-CAPM, D-CAPM, etc. Based on efficient market assumptions, all information is considered in their current prices and any deviation of these variations affects price rapidly. Also, recently, the new behavioral models have connected risk and return using behavioral features of investors. However, the relation between stock value and Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) was not addressed in these models.
On the other hand, recently, observing the noise in financial decision making of individuals, Kahneman and others (2016) has introduced the noise theory. According to this theory, some current risks of stock prices are noise risks or error probabilities in decision making. Generally, the aim of noise theory as an error source is to offer the patterns for decision making to optimize the policies in organizations and financial institutions; thus, the final aim of noise theory is to improve the quality of decision making. The noise theory, in relative terms, can also be as a comparison among different judgments and can decrease the decision-making mistakes of individuals.
So far, several studies are addressed the issue which follows:
Damodaran (2013) studied that how the noises of faire values can influence the bank capital adequacy ratios. If the error of measurement causes the deviation of reported capital levels from the fundamental levels, then legislators can provide a financially healthy bank with a trouble (error type 1) or provide a financially troubled bank with a challenge (error type 2), that results in the allocated unoptimized resources for banks, legislators, and investors. This study has concluded while noise leads to the errors of type I and II around the capital adequacy criteria of the Federal Deposit Insurance Company (FDIC), the type I is superior. Therefore, noise can lead to inefficient allocated resources in the regulatory sections (increasing the supervising costs) and banks (increasing the compliance costs).
Brogaard et. al (2022) reviewed the real effects of stock market efficiency by analyzing how the noise effect on price influences on allocated capital efficiency. In this review, using data of 42 countries, it was concluded that allocated capital efficiency in companies (sensitivity of corporate investment to the opportunities of development) and industries (industrial investment elasticity to value added) is decreased by the noise level.
Cowgill (2018) in a study has developed a formal decision-making model and proved that better learning completes experiments and human judgments in this technology.
Costello and Wats (2014) in their studies have considered systematic biases in possible judgments, commonly as the evidences which emphasize that individuals do not judge probability by rules of probability theory, but they use explorative ways that sometimes result in logical judgment or systematic biases. These views have mainly affected economy, law, medical sciences, etc.
In his study, Hilbert (2014) argues that a single coherent framework for long term researches on eight directions of cognitive decision making, seemingly unrelated, has suggested. During the six past decades, hundreds of experimental studies have led to the rules which determine how individuals are systematically misled about their decisions which are normally expected. Several productive mechanisms were suggested to explain those cognitive prejudices. Now, it is suggested that at least eight decision-making biases, which are experimentally discovered, can be created simply by assumption of noise deviations in the memory-based data process, that turn objective evidences (observations) into subjective estimates (decisions). An integrated framework is offered to show how the similar noise-based mechanisms can lead to conservatism, Bayesian probability orientation, unreal correlation, self-other orientation, secondary orientation, exaggerated expectations, hard-easy trust and effect orientation. Analytical tool of data theory is used to diminish the nature and limitations which explain the information for double and multiple decision making. The next composition offers formal mathematical definitions of biases and mechanisms and their underlying producers, that allows combined analysis of how are their connections. This synthesis helps the bigger target of carving a coherent picture of thousands of orientations seemingly unrelated and their productive psychological mechanisms. The limitations and questions of the research are going to be discussed.
3. Methodology
The present research, according to the above, is based on outcome, applicable, target oriented, descriptive, and based on the type of quantitative data and role of researcher, which is independent of the research strategy and process. This research has used five experts of financial markets, independently, with primary fixed data, to value the stocks of five companies during 1403-1405. Characteristics of the experts are as follows:
Chart 1- Distribution of experts’ work experiences
Chart 2- Distribution of experts’ education
In this study, it is assumed that two factors are the sources of noise effects. The first factor: as there are different methods for calculating the intrinsic value of stocks and these methods do not necessarily lead to the same outputs, one of the noise factors can be the manner of different experts’ decisions, that is used to measure the noise of mean and standard deviation of different methods about the effects of this noise. The second factor: as, because of measurement error in variables used in a method, the different stock valuation is possible, the second source is the risk resulted from different valuation in any method. Considering two source factors of noise risk, at first the standard deviation in any method is calculated, using the following equation:
|
(3) |
|
(4) |
|
(5) |
|
(6) |
|
(7) |
|
FCFE | P/E | DDM | Co. | Expert |
5137 | 3720 | 3386 | Pars petrochemical | Expert 1 |
19672 | 13088 | 13232 | Khalij-e-Fars petrochemical | |
38597 | 11328 | 11015 | Sadid | |
247625 | 188789 | 121657 | Shabandar | |
10176 | 7581 | 8535 | Shapna | |
5820 | 3920 | 3795 | Pars petrochemical | Expert 2 |
20500 | 13500 | 13685 | Khalij-e-Fars petrochemical | |
38652 | 11850 | 11987 | Sadid | |
272990 | 190325 | 122589 | Shabandar | |
10500 | 7895 | 8998 | Shapna | |
6200 | 4292 | 4582 | Pars petrochemical | Expert 3 |
21600 | 14253 | 14652 | Khalij-e-Fars petrochemical | |
38800 | 12543 | 12560 | Sadid | |
275602 | 189523 | 125653 | Shabandar | |
11352 | 8542 | 9586 | Shapna | |
5650 | 4120 | 4231 | Pars petrochemical | Expert 4 |
22000 | 13952 | 13999 | Khalij-e-Fars petrochemical | |
38425 | 12645 | 12502 | Sadid | |
256845 | 189356 | 125024 | Shabandar | |
10352 | 8213 | 9321 | Shapna | |
4652 | 3348 | 2985 | Pars petrochemical | Expert 5 |
17700 | 14250 | 12564 | Khalij-e-Fars petrochemical | |
38150 | 10856 | 10262 | Sadid | |
222860 | 173202 | 119586 | Shabandar | |
10000 | 6985 | 6854 | Shapna |
To measure noise:
In the following table, the results of recognizing noise in valuation of each expert are indicated as percentages:
Table 3- Noise in stock price valuation by experts
Noise (%) | Co. |
15% | Pars petrochemical |
61% | Khalij-e-Fars petrochemical |
14% | Sadid |
12% | Shabandar |
37% | Shapna |
Considering the numbers (12% - 61%) resulted from the experts’ judgments, it can be said that views and analyses of experts on stock valuation are very various. The difference in valuation resulted from different expert views indicates the subject of discussion. The varied views (from 12% to 61%) suggests that experts have different viewpoints in valuating stocks of others. The differences may be due to different interpretations of information, different analysis methods, different experiences in market, or different assumptions to predict the future.
Chart 3- Noise in stock price valuation by experts
Results indicate that noise effects or human judgments can cause meaningful differences in stock price valuation. Human judgment, as an important factor in the process of stock valuation, may be effective because of the following factors:
Firstly, inaccurate predictions – because of incorrect data or interpretations, experts may provide inaccurate predictions which cause meaningful differences in stock valuation.
Secondly, emotional effects – the emotions such as fear, greed, hope may affect expert decision and cause variation of stock valuation. For example, emotions can lead to relative increase or decrease of stock prices, not considering their real values.
Thirdly, group behavior – in stock market, experts and investors may have been influenced by views and opinions of each other, and group decisions may have influenced on valuation, that can cause meaningful differences in stock valuation.
Fourthly, different methods and assumptions – experts can use different methods and assumptions for analyzing. These differences can result in meaningful differences in stock valuation. Generally, stock valuation is a sophisticated function also depended on psychological trends and human factors. To consider these factors and examine more details can help more accurate analysis and better understanding of stock valuation.
Noise is occurred under many factors that few of them are:
The effects of nonlogical factors: experts’ judgments in stock pricing may be influenced by nonlogical factors, including fear, greed, group effect, past price effects, and behavioral deviations. These factors can cause discontinuous and unfair variations in stock price.
Non-identical judgments: experts’ judgments about stock value may be different. This difference can be due to different viewpoints, different valuation models used, different analyzes and assumptions about capital interest rate and profit growth. These differences on judgments can lead to different stock valuation and known as a noise.
Noise of market: noise of market is mentioned as noncontinuous and unfair variations in stock prices because of nonlogical factor effects. The noise can be resulted from experts’ decisions and the analyzes that lead to different stock valuations. Thus, analyzes show that experts’ judgments can create different stock valuations and this difference can be considered as a noise in the stock valuation system. This can present important conclusions on dynamism of financial markets and the roles of nonlogical factors in the process of stock valuation.
Calculating the adjusted beta coefficient:
In this study, beta coefficient was used for calculating the Capital Asset Pricing Model. Beta coefficient points to the fluctuation or risk-taking of stock to the other stocks in market. One of the most common methods to estimate stock beta is using the historical market beta. In this step, as assumed, a part of stock price variation results from noise rate. Using the parameter k calculated before, adjusted beta has been calculated for any time period.
Chart 4- Adjusted beta and beta coefficient in accordance with the noise of stock price valuation (Source: current research results) |
Noise-based Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM):
One financial concern of researchers is to
introduce the stock valuation models in accordance with the real behaviors of investors. So far, many researches have been done about stock pricing modeling. The financial views are developed,
introducing CAPM BY William Sharp in 1962, that defined the relation between risk and return in accordance with β criterion. Although, at first, investors paid attention this model to express the relation between risk and return, during the time, it was recognized that the model sometimes cannot measure well the relation between risk and return. For instance, Basso research (1977) showed that the stocks, which have high prices compared with profits, gain more returns than the stocks with low ratio of profit to price. Or for example, Benz has showed that corporation stocks with low market value have higher average return than corporation stocks with high market value; so, it seems that determining factors other than stock prices affects stock return. Therefore, many efforts are made to improve fundamental models, based on a different look at risk and return. For example, the models such as C-CAPM and D-CAPM are named. In accordance with efficient market assumptions, all data are considered in current prices; and any deviation of these variations affects quickly the prices. However, many exceptions concerning the relation between profit and return in financial markets have voided the efficient market assumptions. These contradictions in efficient market assumptions have created new theories in financial markets like perspective theory by Daniel Kahneman and Amos Torsky in 1979. These theories and many other events such as financial crisis in financial market have led to introduce the financial-behavioral paradigm. According to this paradigm, many rational and economic indexes, that are essential assumptions in traditional pricing models, are voided in real world. Financial-behavioral paradigm, rejecting many assumptions of classic financial-behavioral theories, explains many events in financial markets using some behavioral and personal characteristics of investors. So far, many researches are done to identify kinds of financial biases using behavioral and personal characteristics of investors. One of the asset pricing models is based on behavioral patterns of model X-CAPM that aim to price asset based on behavioral patterns (Barberis, 2013). In this research, attempts have been made also to identify a model to valuate capital asset based on noise (N-CAPM). As it was presented in part 3, the model considered by current research is as follows:
(8) |
|
Table 4- Noise-based Capital Asset Pricing Model (2022) - Source: current research results | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Year | Co. | Beta | Noise | Adjusted beta | CAPM | N-CAPM |
First trimester | Pars petrochemical | 465245/0 | 15/0 | 069787/0 | 138681/2 | 473802/0 |
Second tri. | Pars petrochemical | 018119/1 | 15/0 | 152718/0 | 683536/7 | 30553/1 |
Third tri. | Pars petrochemical | 024995/1 | 15/0 | 153749/0 | 06545/11 | 812817/1 |
Fourth tri. | Pars petrochemical | 953544/0 | 15/0 | 143032/0 | 99098/16 | 701647/2 |
First trimester | Khalij-e-Fars petrochemical | 84469/1 | 61/0 | 125261/1 | 81584/55 | 11786/34 |
Second tri. | Khalij-e-Fars petrochemical | 84469/1 | 61/0 | 125261/1 | 41448/92 | 44303/56 |
Third tri. | Khalij-e-Fars petrochemical | 990364/1 | 61/0 | 214122/1 | 49261/26 | 23069/16 |
Fourth tri. | Khalij-e-Fars petrochemical | 03758/2 | 61/0 | 239982/1 | 91997/70 | 33138/43 |
First trimester | Sadid | 149219/2 | 14/0 | 300891/0 | 28687/36 | 234962/5 |
Second tri. | Sadid | 149219/2 | 14/0 | 300891/0 | 02683/57 | 138556/8 |
Third tri. | Sadid | 933463/1 | 14/0 | 270685/0 | 87369/64 | 237116/9 |
Fourth tri. | Sadid | 933463/1 | 14/0 | 270685/0 | 7151/90 | 85491/12 |
First trimester | Shabandar | 197979/1 | 12/0 | 143757/0 | 05827/13 | 725393/1 |
Second tri. | Shabandar | 197979/1 | 12/0 | 143757/0 | 76508/13 | 81021/1 |
Third tri. | Shabandar | 374857/1 | 12/0 | 164983/0 | 29865/25 | 194238/3 |
Fourth tri. | Shabandar | 92569/1 | 12/0 | 231083/0 | 20944/50 | 183532/6 |
First trimester | Shapna | 450007/1 | 37/0 | 536503/0 | 39916/32 | 10109/12 |
Second tri. | Shapna | 030067/2 | 37/0 | 751125/0 | 970192/8 | 432371/3 |
Third tri. | Shapna | 030067/2 | 37/0 | 751125/0 | 970192/8 | 432371/3 |
Fourth tri. | Shapna | 080841/2 | 37/0 | 769911/0 | 41629/46 | 28743/17 |
Chart 5- Capital Asset Pricing Model compared with Noise-based one - Source: current research results |
5. Discussion
Capital Asset Pricing Model considering human judgments has a meaningful difference with the model which acts not considering the human errors. The pricing model considering human judgments, because of psychological effects and human decisions in decision making trends, may lead to different results than the model not considering these errors. The factors such as risk-taking behaviors, presumptions, and human experiences can have an important impact on the decisions of pricing models; thus, the results of these two models have a meaningful difference with each other and, to choose a suitable model depended on the very cases and condition, the criteria of human judgments
have to be considered.
Considering noise (human judgments) in asset price valuation can prevents fluctuation and inflammation because the amounts resulted for CAPM is placed in the stage of considering noise of less CAPM as well as have less fluctuation; therefore, the assumption has been confirmed. Explaining this conclusion, we
can say that capital asset pricing based on adjusting the human judgments generally cause the resulted amounts, compared with the method based on no human adjustment, are closer to the most real amounts. Because, this method aims to decrease the human factor impacts like recognized errors or definition of value; and consider more information in the asset pricing process. For example, in capital asset pricing, essential factors of main data can be assessed quantitatively; but decision making influenced by human factors such as personal imagines about the value of the asset are important. So, with adjusting the human judgments and using the quantitative data, we can commonly achieve more accurate and real results of capital asset pricing. This can help to increase accuracy of estimating the asset values and guide decision makers to better financial decision making. This conclusion is similar to the one resulted from the studies done by Damodaran (2023), Kahneman et al. (2016), and Hilbert (2014). According to the gained results, the following suggestions are developed:
Market analyzers have to examine carefully the used pricing methods. Do these methods truly consider human judgments? Are human effects adjusted? Therefore, investors are suggested to notice the suitable human behaviors and the limitations which they have to consider in their decision making.
It is suggested that market analyzers and investors participate in the scientific researches on the roles of human judgments in stock valuation and use the newest achievements of this field. Also, continuous training of market analyzers and investors on better methods of risk management and valuation, considering human factors, is necessary. As well as, taking risk management strategies, considering human judgment effects and possible investors’ behaviors in different market condition for decision makers and analyzers, are effective and using the method based on data and artificial intelligence to analyze more accurate and improve predictions considering human role in decision making of market in this field will be effective.
6. References
Acharya, V. V. and Pedersen, L. H. (2005). Asset pricing with liquidity risk. Journal of financial Economics, 77(2):375–410.
Adler, M. and Dumas, B. (1983). International portfolio choice and corporation finance: A synthesis. The Journal of Finance, 38(3):925–984
Barberis, N. and Thaler, R. (2013). A Survey of Behavioral Finance. Handbook of the Economics of Finance, North-Holland, Amsterdam.
Bawa, V. S. and Lindenberg, E. B. (1977). Capital market equilibrium in a mean-lower partial moment framework. Journal of financial economics, 5(2):189–200.
Black, F., Jensen, M. C., Scholes, M., et al. (1972). The capital asset pricing model: Some empirical tests.
Bodie, Z., Kane, A., and Marcus, A. (2013). EBOOK: Essentials of Investments: Global Edition. McGraw Hill.
Breeden, D. T. (1979). An intertemporal asset pricing model with stochastic consumption and investment opportunities. Journal of financial Economics,7(3):265–296
Brock, W. A. (1982). Asset prices in a production economy. In The economics of information and uncertainty, pages 1–46. University of Chicago Press.
Cochrane, J. H. (1991). Production-based asset pricing and the link between stock returns and economic fluctuations. The Journal of Finance, 46(1):209–237.
Costello, F. Watts, P. (2014), Probability theory plus noise explains biases in judgment, National University of Ireland
Cowgill, B. (2018). Bias and Productivity in Humans and Algorithms: Theory and Evidence from R´esum´e Screening, Columbia University
Damodaran, Aswath, Living with Noise: Valuation in the Face of Uncertainty (2023). Journal of Applied Finance (Formerly Financial Practice and Education), Vol. 23, No. 2, 2013, Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2684015
Fama, E. F. and French, K. R. (1993). Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds. Journal of financial economics, 33(1):3–56.
Fang, H. and Lai, T.-Y. (1997). Co-kurtosis and capital asset pricing. Financial Review, 32(2):293–307.
Harlow, W. V. and Rao, R. K. (1989). Asset pricing in a generalized mean-lower partial moment framework: Theory and evidence. Journal of financial and quantitative analysis, 24(3):285–311.
Hilbert, M., (2014), Toward a Synthesis of Cognitive Biases: How Noisy Information Processing Can Bias Human Decision Making, Article in Psychological Bulletin
Hogan, W. W. and Warren, J. M. (1974). Toward the development of an equilibrium capital-market model based on semi variance. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 9(1):1–11.
Jagannathan, R. and Wang, Z. (1996). The conditional capm and the cross-section of expected returns. The Journal of finance, 51(1):3–53.
Jensen, M. C. (1968). The performance of mutual funds in the period 1945-1964. The Journal of finance, 23(2):389–416
Kahneman, D., Rosenfield, A.M., Gandhi, L., Blaser, T. (2016). Reducing Noise in Decision Making. Harvard Business Review, 94(12), 18-18.
Kraus, A. and Litzenberger, R. H. (1976). Skewness preference and the valuation of risk assets. The Journal of finance, 31(4):1085–1100
Lucas Jr, R. E. (1978). Asset prices in an exchange economy. Econometrica: journal of the Econometric Society, pages 1429–1445.
Levy, H. (2010). The capm is alive and well: A review and synthesis. European Financial Management, 16(1):43–71.
Markowitz, H. (1952). Portfolio selection. Journal of Finance, 7(1):77–91.
Mayers, D. (1973). Nonmarketable assets and the determination of capital asset prices in the absence of a riskless asset. The Journal of Business, 46(2):258–267.
McGoun, E. G. (1993). The capm: a nobel failure. Critical Perspectives on Accounting, 4(2):155–177
Merton, R. C. (1973). An intertemporal capital asset pricing model. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, pages 867–
Mossin, J. (1966). Equilibrium in a capital asset market. Econometrica: Journal of the econometric society, pages 768–783.
Lintner, J. (1965). The valuation (or risk assets and the selection (or risky investments in stock portrolios and capital, budgets. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 47(1):13–37
Ross, S. A. (1976). Options and efficiency. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 90(1):75–89.
Rubinstein, M. E. (1973). A mean-variance synthesis of corporate financial theory. The Journal of Finance, 28(1):167–181.
Sharpe, W. F. (1964). Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk. The journal of finance, 19(3):425–442.
Solnik, B. H. (1974). An equilibrium model of the international capital market. Journal of economic theory, 8(4):500–524
Zarifhonarvar, A., (2023), The Capital Asset Pricing Model: A New Empirical Investigation, ZBW - Leibniz Information Centre for Economics, Kiel, Hamburg
HOW TO CITE THIS ARTICLE:
Barasoud M., Zomorodian G., Rahnama Rudpashti F. (2023). Developing the Capital Asset Pricing Model Using the Noise Based Behavioral Model (N-CAPM), 4(4): 63-78.
DOI:
Url:
Journal homepage: https://sanad.iau.ir/journal/ijfaes/