کاربرد مدل نظریه بازی چندهدفه در تعیین تعادل اقتصادی-محیط زیستی حوضه آبخیز دریاچه زریبار مریوان
محورهای موضوعی : فصلنامه علمی برنامه ریزی منطقه ایمحمد علی اسعدی 1 , محمدحسن وکیل پور 2 , سید ابوالقاسم مرتضوی 3 , کامران عبدالهی 4
1 - دانشجوی دکتری گروه اقتصاد کشاورزی دانشگاه تربیت مدرس، تهران، ایران.
2 - دکتری گروه اقتصاد کشاورزی دانشگاه تربیت مدرس، تهران، ایران.
3 - استادیار گروه اقتصاد کشاورزی دانشگاه تربیت مدرس، تهران، ایران.
4 - دانش آموخته کارشناسی ارشد گروه اقتصاد کشاورزی دانشگاه تربیت مدرس، تهران، ایران.
کلید واژه: تعادل اقتصادی-محیط زیستی, مدل چندهدفه نظریه بازی, تعادل نش, تعادل پارتو, دریاچه زریبار,
چکیده مقاله :
یکی از مهمترین چالشهای فراروی مدیریت حوزه آبخیز، وجود تعارض بین سود اقتصادی و حفظ محیطزیست در عرصه آبخیزهاست که باعث ایجاد مشکلات زیادی مانند تغییر کاربری اراضی توسط آبخیزنشینان با هدف افزایش سود اقتصادی، بدون در نظر گرفتن سلامت آبخیزها میشود. در این پژوهش یک مدل چندهدفه نظریه بازی (MOGT) بهعنوان ابزاری جایگزین برای حل تعارضات راهبردی یعنی توسعه اقتصادی (توسعه و کاربرد زمین) و حفاظت از محیطزیست (حفظ کیفیت آب و کاهش مواد آلاینده) بسط داده شد که برای تصمیمگیری و موازنه چالشهای اقتصادی- محیطزیستی حوضه آبخیز دریاچه زریبار مریوان در استان کردستان صورت گرفته است. برای محاسبه و نمایش انواع گوناگون کاربریهای اراضی از سیستم اطلاعات جغرافیایی (GIS) بهره گرفته شده است. در این پژوهش حامیان و طرفداران حفاظت از محیطزیست بهعنوان بازیگر نخست (بازیگر محیطزیستی) و کاربران حوزه آبخیز دریاچه بهعنوان بازیگر دوم (بازیگر اقتصادی) انتخاب شدند. نتایج مدل چندهدفه نظریه بازیها نشان داد که پس از هفت دور چانهزنی و تعدیل اهداف بین بازیگران، تعادل نش ایجاد شد که در این حالت تعادل بین دغدغههای محیطزیستی و اقتصادی در مدیریت آبخیز برقرار شده است. تعادل نش برای بازیگر محیطزیستی در بازه 25365 تا 25366 کیلوگرم در هکتار و مقدار درآمد برای بازیگر اقتصادی از 420 تا 421 میلیون ریال در سال متغیر است. از دیگر نتایج پژوهش نشان داد که حل مدل تصمیمگیری چندهدفه برای حوضه آبخیز دریاچه، منجر به دستیابی به راهحل بهینه پارتو نشده است بلکه دامنهای از جوابها حاصل شده است. با مقایسه نتایج مدل برنامهریزی معمولی چندهدفه و مدل بازی بر مبنای دورهای چانهزنی، برتری مدل MOGT نسبت به مدل متعارف برنامهریزی چندهدفه مورد تأیید قرار گرفت و میتواند راهحلهای رضایتبخشتری بر اساس اولویتهای تصمیمگیرندگان ارائه دهد. یافتههای این پژوهش میتواند در مدیریت کاربری زمین در آبخیزها و در شرایطی که بین اهداف اقتصادی و محیطزیستی تضاد بهوجود میآید، به کار رود.
One of the most important challenges facing watershed management is the conflict between economic benefit of stakeholders and environmental protection in watersheds that in turn causes many problems such as land use change by stakeholders to increase profit, regardless of watersheds health problems. In this study, a multi-objective game theory (MOGT) model was developed as an alternative tool for resolving strategic conflicts, namely economic development (development and land use) and environmental protection (water quality preservation and reduction of pollutants) that was developed to decision making and balance the economic-environmental challenges of the Marivan Zrebar Lake watershed in Kurdistan province. Geographic information system (GIS) has been used to calculate and display different types of land uses. In this study, the environmentalists (player 1) and Zrebar basin users (player 2) were selected as environmental and economical players, respectively. The results of multi-objective game-theory model indicated that Nash equilibrium was established after seven rounds of bargaining and moderating the objectives between players and the balance between environmental and economic concerns in watershed management was established. Nash equilibrium varies for environmental actor ranges from 25365 to 25366 kg/ha and income for economic actor from 420 to 421 million Rials per year. The results also indicated that solving the multi-objective decision making model for the lake watershed does not result in a Pareto optimal, but rather a range of solutions. By comparing the results of the classical multi-objective planning model and the game theory based on rounds of bargaining, the MOGT model is superior to the clasical multi-objective model and can provide more satisfactory solutions based on decision makers' preferences. Findings of this research can be useful for land use change management in the watershed where there is conflict between economic and environmental concerns.
Extended Abstract
Introduction:
Decision makers often have difficulty adopting the appropriate choice from among sundry uses of a watershed (Madani, 2010). Decision making is highly controversial due to conflicting criteria (Lee & Chang, 2005); in view of the fact that each user's behavior with different views, values, and interests also affects the choice and interests of others (Shields et al, 1999). Of discussions related to watershed management, there has been dispute concerning economic revenues from land development (deforestation, agriculture and recreational activities), environmental objectives (pollution reduction) and socio-economic plans (soil and water conservation) (Lund & Palmer, 1997). Looking at it from a scientific point of view, most of this controversy has focused on finding the pareto optimal solution (Madani, 2010). In other words, there must be a balance between increasing economic profits and reducing negative environmental impacts. In situations where objectives contradict each other, improvement regarding one goal is achieved at the cost of overlooking another goal or reducing the likelihood of achieving it (Raquel et al, 2007). Among methods aim at tackling such issues in conflict situations is the multi-objective model of game theory.
Methodology:
In this study, as the first step, a linear optimization model with two economic and environmental objectives was developed to maximize the profit of the users living next to the Zrebar Lake basin and to minimize the environmental pollution of the lands around (conventional model). The optimal solution of the pareto is obtained via employing this model. From an economic point of view, in order for the lands in a watershed to generate maximum income, they must be allocated to different uses. On the other hand, from an environmental point of view, watershed lands should not be exploited more than their respective capacity range. At this stage, the contradiction between economic and environmental objectives is clearly visible; because the nature of Pareto's optimal solution is such that any improvement with respect to one objective is achieved simply by degrading one other objective. As the second step, in order to resolve the conflict between economic and environmental objectives, they confront one another, and Nash equilibrium will be established through the bargaining process (game model). The Nash equilibrium feature attained from the algorithmic bargaining process ensures that each player has made the best decision against the constraints imposed by the second player. The essential data were collected by segregation of the region based on different uses of the land of the watershed, using the Geographic Information System (GIS), and the plans made in the Zrebar watershed during 2015-2016. In order to solve the multi-objective decision problem, the ArcGis Desktop 9.0 software package was used to extract accurate data.
Results and discussion:
In the present study, for the economic player, the goal was to maximize income, which includes agricultural, horticultural, tourism-recreational, industrial and animal husbandry activities. For the second player, the minimum concentration of phosphorus and nitrogen was considered as the environmental objective. First, each player identifies the maximum and minimum values by analyzing the single-objective function. The primary objective for the first player (environmental player) equals the lowest possible pollution level of EnvPmin = 19840 kg per hectare per year, while the primary objective for the second player (economic player) is to earn the highest possible income, ie EcoDmax =56500000 Rials per hectare per year. Since the initial results of the simulation of the multi-objective model are not satisfactory with respect to each player, both entered the first round of negotiations. During the bargaining process, players moderate their objectives. The strategy of the first player was set to increase from 20,000 to 25,365 kilograms per hectare, and the strategy of the second player was set to decrease from 54 to 42.1 million rials per hectare. The greater the difference between the values shown and the values obtained from the optimization process, the closer to the real equilibrium point. After the seventh round of bargaining, the value of EnvP = 25365 obtained by solving the mathematical programming model is approximately equal to the value determined by the environmental player, and the EcoD value is approximately equal to the value determined by the economic player. The results at this stage are satisfactory for both players and therefore they reached the Nash equilibrium point.
Conclusion:
The current study aimed at evaluating the feasibility of using the multi-objective Game Theory (MOGM) model to fashion a balance between economic and environmental challenges in optimizing land use in the watershed of Zrebar Lake in Marivan and to help ease the decision-making process. Supporters and advocates for environment and forests protection were selected as the first player (environmental player) and users of the Zrebar Lake watershed as the second player (economic player). The results indicated that:
Using the multi-objective decision-making model for the lake's watershed has not led to an optimal solution of the Pareto, but to a range of solutions.
In the game model, each player takes actions for his personal interests, but in the conventional multi-objective model, players take initiative to improve the interests of the whole system. What is more likely to happen in the real world is that people prefer personal interests to collective ones. Overfishing, poaching, excessive water pumping, illegal well drilling, etc. are all considered reasons for the benefit of individualism in the real world. Nash equilibrium will scientifically describe such behavior.
In balance mode, the level of cultivation of crops like wheat and barley was constant, but garden products, summer crops, vegetables and straw-covered fields have been removed from the model. This indicates that these kinds of activity have not been compatible with environmental objectives.
By comparing the results of the conventional multi-objective programming model and the game model based on bargaining rounds, the superiority of the MOGT model was confirmed over the conventional multi-objective programming model. Therefore, it is recommended to consider the best measures affecting water quality and increasing income, such as replacing the new source of livelihood, reducing the use of fertilizers, replacing vegetable and fruit cultivation instead of wheat.
1- Abdoli, Gh. (2014). Game theory and its applications (static and dynamic games of complete information). Tehran, Jahad Daneshgahi Press, 454 pages (in Persian).
2- Barari, M., Bagheri, A., & Hashemi, S.M. (2016). Analysis of the issues of Lake Zrêbar in a context of Integrated Water Resources Management using a stakeholders' participatory approach in a basin scale. Water Resource Management, 12(2), 1-12 (in Persian).
3- Bartolini, F., Bazzani, G. M., Gallerani, V., Raggi, M., & Viaggi, D. (2007). The impact of water and agriculture policy scenarios on irrigated farming systems in Italy: An analysis based on farm level multi-attribute linear programming models. Agricultural systems, 93(1-3), 90-114.
4- Behrouzirad, B. (2008). Iranian wetlands. Tehran: Geographical Organization of the Armed Forces Publications (in Persian).
5- Bennett, P. G. (1980). Hypergames: developing a model of conflict. Futures, 12(6), 489-507.
6- Berbel, J., & Gómez-Limón, J. A. (2000). The impact of water-pricing policy in Spain: an analysis of three irrigated areas. Agricultural Water Management, 43(2), 219-238.
7- Bruckmeier, K. (2005). Interdisciplinary conflict analysis and conflict mitigation in local resource management. AMBIO: A Journal of the Human Environment, 34(2), 65-73.
8- Carraro, C., Marchiori, C., & Sgobbi, A. (2005). Applications of negotiation theory to water issues. The World Bank.
9- Carraro, C., Marchiori, C., & Sgobbi, A. (2007). Negotiating on water: insights from non-cooperative bargaining theory. Environment and Development Economics, 12(2), 329-349.
10- Chhipi-Shrestha, G., Rodriguez, M., & Sadiq, R. (2019). Selection of sustainable municipal water reuse applications by multi-stakeholders using game theory. Science of The Total Environment, 650, 2512-2526.
11- Cohon, J. L. (2004). Multiobjective programming and planning (Vol. 140). Courier Corporation.
12- Dinar, A. (2004). Exploring transboundary water conflict and cooperation. Water Resources Research, 40(5).
13- Farman, E., & Mostafa, A. (2015). Environmental characteristics of lake Zaribvar (Marivan, Kurdistan Province) according to water resources management. The first international conference and the fourth national conference on environmental and agricultural research of Iran (in Persian).
14- Francisco, S. R., & Ali, M. (2006). Resource allocation tradeoffs in Manila’s peri-urban vegetable production systems: An application of multiple objective programming. Agricultural Systems, 87(2), 147-168.
15- Fraser, N.M., & Hipel, K.W. )1984(. Conflict Analysis: Models and Resolutions. North- Holland, Amsterdam, New York, USA.
16- Gibbons, R. (1997). An introduction to applicable game theory. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11(1), 127-149.
17- Giordano, R., Passarella, G., Uricchio, V. F., & Vurro, M. (2005). Fuzzy cognitive maps for issue identification in a water resources conflict resolution system. Physics and Chemistry of the Earth, Parts A/B/C, 30(6-7), 463-469.
18- Goicoechea, A., Hansen, D. R., & Duckstein, L. (1982). Multiobjective decision analysis with engineering and business applications (No. BOOK). John Wiley & Sons.
19- Harboe, R. (1992). Multiobjective decision making techniques for reservoir operation. Journal of the American Water Resources Association, 28(1), 103-110.
20- Harsanyi, J. C. (1973). Paradoxes of Rationality: Theory of Metagames and Political Behavior. By Nigel Howard.(Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1971. Pp. 248. $12.95.). American Political Science Review, 67(2), 599-600.
21- Hasti, F., SalmanMahiny, A., &Joolaie, R. (2016). Spatial optimization using goal programming, Game Theory and GIS. Town and Country Planning, 8(2), 203-228 (in Persian).
22- Hipel, K. W., Kilgour, D. M., Fang, L., & Peng, X. J. (1997). The decision support system GMCR in environmental conflict management. Applied Mathematics and Computation, 83(2-3), 117-152.
23- Howard, N. )1999(. Confrontation Analysis: How to Win Operations Other Than War. CCRP Publications, Pentagon, Washington, DC, USA.
24- Hwang, C.-L., & Masud, A. S. M. (1979). Multiple objective decision making. Berlin: Springer-Verlag. Joeres, E. F., Dressler, J., Cho, C.-C. And Falkner, C. H. (1974). Planning Methodology for The Design Of Regional Waste Water Treatment Systems. Water Resources Research, 10(4), 643–649.
25- Kilgour, D. M., Fang, L., & Hipel, K. W. (1996). Negotiation support using the decision support system GMCR. Group Decision and Negotiation, 5(4-6), 371-383.
26- Latinopoulos, D., & Mylopoulos, Y. (2005). Optimal allocation of land and water resources in irrigated agriculture by means of goal programming: Application in Loudias river basin. Global nest. The international journal, 7(3), 264-273.
27- Lee, C. S., & Chang, S. P. (2005). Interactive fuzzy optimization for an economic and environmental balance in a river system. Water research, 39(1), 221-231.
28- Lee, C.S. (2012). Multi-objective game theory models for conflict analysis in reservoir watershed management. Chemosphere, 87(6), 608–613.
29- Lest L, Y. Y. (1977). Hierarchical analysis of water resources systems. New York: Mcgraw-Hill.
30- Li, K. W., Hipel, K. W., Kilgour, D. M., & Fang, L. (2004). Preference uncertainty in the graph model for conflict resolution. IEEE Transactions on Systems, Man, and Cybernetics-Part A: Systems and Humans, 34(4), 507-520.
31- Losa, F. B., van den Honert, R., & Joubert, A. (2001). The multivariate analysis biplot as tool for conflict analysis in MCDA. Journal of Multi‐Criteria Decision Analysis, 10(5), 273-284.
32- Lund, J. R., & Palmer, R. N. (1997). Water resource system modeling for conflict resolution. Water Resources Update, 3(108), 70-82.
33- Madani, K. (2010). Game theory and water resources. Journal of Hydrology, 381(3-4), 225-238.
34- Massoud, T. G. (2000). Fair division, adjusted winner procedure (AW), and the Israeli-Palestinian conflict. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 44(3), 333-358.
35- Moradi, S., & Mohammadi Limaei, S. (2018). Application of multi-objective game-theory model for the purpose of land use optimization of Zemkan basin. Watershed Engineering and Management, 2(3), 432-445 (in Persian).
36- Navidi, H.R., Ketabchi, S., & Messi Bidgoli, M. (2011). An introduction to game theory. Tehran, Shahed University Press, 348 pages (in Persian)
37- Osborne, M. J., & Rubinstein, A. (1994). A course in game theory. MIT press.
38- Regional Water Compani of Kordestan. (2014). Annual Climate Change Report (in Persian).
39- Semaan, J., Flichman, G., Scardigno, A., & Steduto, P. (2007). Analysis of nitrate pollution control policies in the irrigated agriculture of Apulia Region (Southern Italy): A bio-economic modelling approach. Agricultural Systems, 94(2), 357-367.
40- Shields, D. J., Tolwinski, B., & Kent, B. M. (1999). Models for conflict resolution in ecosystem management. Socio-Economic Planning Sciences, 33(1), 61-84.
41- Sobhanardakani, S., Mahmodnezhad, S. & Heydari, M. (2017). Investigation of heavy metals pollution in Marivan River water during spring and summer of 2013. Journal of Research in Environmental Health, 2(4), 311-320.
42- Thiessen, E. M., & Loucks, D. P. )1992(. Computer-assisted negotiation of multiobjective water resources conflicts. Water Resources Bulletin 28 (1), 163–177.
43- Thiessen, E. M., Loucks, D. P., & Stedinger, J. R. (1998). Computer-assisted negotiations of water resources conflicts. Group Decision and Negotiation, 7(2), 109-129.
44- Üçler, N., Engin, G. O., Köçken, H. G., & Öncel, M. S. (2015). Game theory and fuzzy programming approaches for bi-objective optimization of reservoir watershed management: a case study in Namazgah reservoir. Environmental Science and Pollution Research, 22(9), 6546-6558.
45- Wang, M., Hipel, K. W., & Fraser, N. M. (1988). Modeling misperceptions in games. Behavioral Science, 33(3), 207-223.
Behavioral Science, 33(3), 207-223.
_||_