Optimal Inflation Rate Measurement for Minimizing Economic Inequality: The Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Approach
Subject Areas : Financial EconomicsAlireza Azizi 1 , Hashem Zare 2 , Abbas Aminifard 3 , Jalil Khodaparast Shirazi 4
1 - Department of Economics, Shiraz Branch, Islamic Azad University, Shiraz, Iran
2 - Department of Economic, Shiraz Branch, Islamic Azad University, Shiraz, Iran
3 - Department of Economic, Shiraz Branch, Islamic Azad University, Shiraz, Iran
4 - Department of Economic, Shiraz Branch, Islamic Azad University, Shiraz, Iran
Keywords: Optimal Inflation Rate, Distribution of Income, Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium(DSGE),
Abstract :
The equitable distribution of income is considered as a development indicator in countries. Thus it is required to identify factors impacting the equitable distribution of income to make suitable policies to improve it. The present study aims to determine the optimal inflation rate in order to minimize income inequality by using the dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) method in Iran during 1997-2017. The results revealed the optimal inflation rate to be 3.74%. An increase or reduction in the optimal inflation rate of 3.74% enhances income inequality. Thus, the government should target the inflation rate in its policies to achieve minimum inequality. Hence, inequality fluctuations (rises and declines) will be probable.
[1] Eslami, S., reviewing the effects of some macroeconomic variables on income gap (cost), Quarterly of Financial and Economic Policies, 2014; 3 (7): 31-56.
[2] Abounouri, E., Effects of macroeconomic indexes on income distribution in Iran, Economic Research Magazine, 1997; 51.
[3] Abounouri, A., Mofatteh, S., and Parhizigashti, H., Analyzing the effects of inflation on income distribution in Iran: a comparative analysis of rural and urban regions in Iran, Quarterly of Economic Sciences, 2010; 4(13): 77-96.
[4] Ahmadian, A., Modeling bank run in the framework of DSGE for Iran, Science-research Magazine of Economic Policy-making, 2015; 7(14).
[5] Amini, A., Haji, M., Estimating the time series of capital balance in the economy of Iran during 2002-2008, Planning and Budget Magazine, 2005; 19: 53-86.
[6] Bakhshidastgerdi, R., Sheykhansari, M., Effects of commercial banks and population growth on optimal inflation in Sidrauski’s model for the economy of Iran, Quarterly of quantitative economy (former economic investigations magazine), 2015; 12(13): 117-140.
[7] Tashkini, A., Afzali, H., measuring optimal inflation: a case study of Iran’s economy, Quarterly of Economic Studies and Policies, 2011; 19(59):101-128.
[8] Zakerhanji, H. and Mehran, F., economic growth and income inequality in Iran, Statistical Center of Iran, National Calculations Office, 1977.
[9] Tavakolian, H., Investigating a new Keynesian Phillips curve in the form of a DSGE model for Iran, Magazine of Economic Studies, 2012; 3: 1-22.
[10] Hajikhodazadeh, H., Analyzing Iran’s economy growth sources by using Ozawa-Lucas optimal growth pattern calibration, Master’s Thesis, Faculty of Economics and Management, University of Yazd, Yazd, Iran, 2012.
[11] Jalali, M., investigating and analyzing inequality variations in income distribution and their effects on inflation in Iran, Ravand Quarterly, 2016; 23(75): 45-66.
[12] Balcilar, M., Chang, S., Gupta, R. et al. The relationship between the inflation rate and inequality across U.S. states: a semiparametric approach. Qual Quant. 2018; 52: 2413–2425. Doi: 10.1007/s11135-017-0676-3
[13] Zaeri, M. and Nodari, K., Calculating the inflation welfare cost in Iran, Economic Strategy in Iran, 2013; 4: 39-70.
[14] Zibaei, H., Evaluating the contributions of factors determining income inequality and distribution in Iran, Scientific-promotional Magazine, 2005; 91: 29-68.
[15] Ramsey, F.P., A Mathematical Theory of Saving, Economic Journal, 1928; 38, 543-559. Doi:10.2307/2224098
[16] Shakeri, A., Jahangard, E., and Aghlami, S., The nonlinear impact of inflation on income inequality in Iran, Quarterly of Economic Studies (Sustainable Growth and Development), 2013; 13(4): 27-53.
[17] Sayyadi, M., Daneshjafari, D., Bahrami, J., and Raferi, M., Proposing a framework for optimally using oil revenues in Iran: A DSGE approach, Science-research Quarterly of Planning and Budget, 2015; 20(2): 21-58.
[18] Ebadatian, Z., Taghinejad, O., and Gilak-Hakimabadi, M., Optimal inflation rate in Iran: a final welfare cost solution, Master’s Thesis, University of Mazandaran, 2012.
[19] Asgari, A., An overview of inflation and income distribution in Iran, Monthly of Trade Studies, 1991; 51.
[20] Farahmandmanesh, A., and Armanmehr, M., Investigating the effects of income inequality among urban households in Iran with the Atkinson approach, Quarterly of Economic and Regional Development Studies, 2018; 15: 25-38.
[21] Komeyjani, A., and Mohammadzadeh, F., Effects of inflation on income distribution and compensating policies’ performance, Quarterly of Economic Studies and Policies, 2014; 22(69): 5-24.
[22] Gorji, Borhanipour, Effects of globalization on income distribution, Quarterly of Iran’s Economic Studies, 2008;10(33): 99-124.
[23] Golkhandan, A., Threshold effects of inflation on income inequality in Iran: The Smooth transition regression (STR) model, Economic Inquiries of Iran, 2016;13(25): 75-95.
[24] Hadizonouz, B., Poverty and income inequality in Iran, Quarterly of Social Welfare, 2010; 17: 35-48.
[25] Mirbagherihayyer, M., and Shokouhifard, S., Adaptive investigation of the effects of financial development on income distribution and poverty in selected Islamic countries: A panel data approach, Science-research Quarterly of Economic Growth and Development Studies, 2016; 25: 93-108.
[26] Nazari, R., Mazaheri, L., The relationship between inflation and income distribution in Iran, Political-Economic Quarterly, 2011; 284.
[27] Hadia, A. and Izadi, B., Investigating the effects of inflation in financial development effectiveness on economic growth in Iran, Quarterly of Economic Development Studies, 2014; 15: 45-72.
[28] Kafaei, S., and Moradbeygi, M. (2010), Inflation inequality in Iran in details, Economics Quarterly of Shahid Beheshti University, 1st year, No. 2, p. 31-51.
[29] Statistical Center of Iran ,2018.
[30] Lorenzo Menna, Patrizio Tirelli, Optimal inflation to reduce inequality, Review of Economic Dynamics, 2017; 24: 79-94, Doi: 10.1016/j.red.2017.01.004.
[31] Christina Romer and David Romer, Proceedings - Economic Policy Symposium - Jackson Hole, 1998; 159-201
[32] Zaker Hanjani, H., Income Inequality Measurement in Iran, refahj, 2007; 6(24): 83-104.
[33] GĂĽnter, C., McAdam, P., Straub, R., Tax reform and labourmarket performance in the euro area: A simulation-based analysis using the New Area-Wide Model, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 2008; 32(8): 2543-2583. Doi: 10.1016/j.jedc.2007.09.007.
[34] John, H., Boyd, R., Levine, B., Smith, D., The impact of inflation on financial sector performance, Journal of Monetary Economics, 2001; 47(2): 221-248,Doi:10.1016/S0304-3932(01)00049-6.
[35] Huybens, E., Smith, B., Inflation, Financial Markets and Long-Run Real Activity, Journal of Monetary Economics, 1999; 43: 283-315. Doi:10.1016/S0304-3932(98)00060-9
[36] Huybens, E., Smith, Bruce D., Financial Market Frictions, Monetary Policy, and Capital Accumulation in a Small Open Economy, Journal of Economic Theory, Elsevier, 1998; 81(2): 353-400,
[37] Rousseau, Peter L., Yilmazkuday, H., Inflation, financial development, and growth: A trilateral analysis, Economic Systems, Elsevier, 2009; 33(4): 310-324.
[38] Martin, J., Bailey, The Welfare Cost of Inflationary Finance, Journal of Political Economy, 1956; 64(2), Doi: abs/10.1086/257766
[39] Hadian, E., Izady, B. Determining the optimal rate of housing facilities and investigating its role on the link between facilities and the housing price index in Iran. Urban Economics, 2020; 5(2): 113-122. Doi: 10.22108/ue.2022.131969.1201
[40] Deyshappriya, NR., The causality direction of the stock market–growth nexus: application of GMM dynamic panel data and the panel ganger non-causality tests. Margin: The Journal of Applied Economic Research. 2016 Nov; 10(4): 446-64.
[41] Monnin, P., Inflation and Income Inequality in Developed Economies, CEP Working Paper Series, June 2, 2014; Doi:10.2139/ssrn.2444710
[42] Thalassinos, Eleftherios Ioannis and Liapis, Konstantinos and Politis, Evangelos, Shipping Companies Profitability Measurement: A Panel Data Analysis , March 26, 2015. Doi:10.2139/ssrn.2693003
[43] Hitoshi, F., Nobuyuki, O., Hiroshi, U., Optimal inflation for Japan's economy, Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 2008; 22(4): 439-475, ISSN 0889-1583, Doi:10.1016/j.jjie.2008.08.001
[44] Bulir, A., The impact of macroeconomic policies on the distribution of income, Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics, 2001 Jun; 72(2): 253-70.
[45] Bulir, MA. The price incentive to smuggle and the cocoa supply in Ghana, 1950-96. International Monetary Fund; 1998 Jun 1.
[46] Bulir, MA., Gulde, MA., Inflation and Income Distribution: Further Evidence on Empirical Links, International Monetary Fund; 1995 Aug 1.
[47] Parker, SK., Enhancing role breadth self-efficacy: the roles of job enrichment and other organizational interventions, Journal of applied psychology, 1998 Dec;83(6):835.
[48] Fiorino, N., Galli, E., An analysis of the determinants of corruption: Evidence from the Italian regions. Monograph Book. Doi:10.4337/9781782544302.00009
[49] Sahota, GS., Theories of personal income distribution: a survey, Journal of Economic Literature. 1978 Mar 1;16(1):1-55.
[50] Tower, J., Hsps and aging. Trends in Endocrinology & Metabolism. 2009; 20(5):216-22.
Original Research
Optimal Inflation Rate Measurement for Minimizing Economic Inequality: The Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Approach
Alireza Azizi, Hashem Zare*, Abbas Aminifard, Jalil Khodaparast Shirazi
Department of Economics, Faculty of Economics and Management, Shiraz Branch, Islamic Azad University, Shiraz, Iran | ||
Article Info Article history: Received 2022-08-31 Accepted 2023-02-23
Keywords: Optimal Inflation Rate Distribution of Income Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium(DSGE)
|
| Abstract |
The equitable distribution of income is considered as a development indicator in countries. Thus it is required to identify factors impacting the equitable distribution of income to make suitable policies to improve it. The present study aims to determine the optimal inflation rate in order to minimize income inequality by using the dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) method in Iran during 1997-2017. The results revealed the optimal inflation rate to be 3.74%. An increase or reduction in the optimal inflation rate of 3.74% enhances income inequality. Thus, the government should target the inflation rate in its policies to achieve minimum inequality. Hence, inequality fluctuations (rises and declines) will be probable.
|
1 Introduction
Inflation is among the most important factors impacting the inequitable distribution of income in the economic literature. It is an essential problem in economics and imposes numerous negative impacts, including non-optimal resource allocation, income inequality, slow economic growth, and future uncertainty. These problems are so important that almost no economic study can ignore inflation (Many researchers in the literature attempted to find solutions to reduce inflation. Some researchers claimed inflation to result from the major deficiencies of capitalism) [15]. Given the inverse relationship between the inflation rate and the unemployment rate and its impact on the improvement of production and employment, inflation is inevitable in incomplete employment status. However, the main problem is that what the optimal policy-induced inflation rate should be to not only avoid rising income inequality (Distribution of income is a well-known context in the economic literature of Iran; however, despite its considerable extensiveness, it has not enjoyed the required deepness. Michael Todaro proposed a short and valid definition for national income distribution as “Who earns how much of what” [3].) while producing the maximum effectiveness but also improve it.
Economic changes in countries in recent years, particularly in developing countries that experienced a larger income gap among different classes of their societies in spite of their relative economic growth have made economists and policy-makers pay more attention to the distribution of income and reduce income differences and consequent social tensions by making optimal economic policies (The concept of income inequality has been the subject of many philosophers, statistical researchers, political theorists, sociologists, and economists. The complication of measuring this concept begins from the fact that “income inequality” creates different concepts in the minds of different individuals, depending on their prejudice and knowledge) [32]. since inflation reduces purchasing power and harms those that have fixed income and those that cannot increase their income as inflation rises [12]. At the same time, inflation decreases the values of government transfer payments, such as cash subsidies and employment insurance payments. Thus, as transfer payment receivers typically come from the most impoverished class of society, inflation will enhance inequality if such payments are not adjusted based on inflation. Inflation also decreases inequality by reducing the real values of monetary assets since the poor have a larger portion of their monetary assets in the form of cash than the rich and thus, they are more exposed to the inflation-reduced purchasing power [12]. The difference in the power of different classes to hedge inflation effects is the most important impact of inflation on inequality. Richer classes are typically abler to protect themselves against inflation-caused shocks. They can invest in a group of assets whose returns either have a weak correlation with inflation or can grow at a higher rate than the inflation rate on average, hedge the effect of inflation. This is not easy for low-income classes since such activities require a minimum level of assets due to the incompleteness of investment and financial markets, and such classes cannot provide it.
Hence, the inflation tax asymmetry resulting from the unequal distribution of wealth is a major reason in support of price stability since monetary assets account for a large portion of the portfolios of low-income households. Thus, the inflation tax burden is inappropriately imposed on the poor. In other words, this is a key justification for confirming price stability as a contribution to the reduction of inequality and poverty. Moligan and Salay-Martin indicated that the chance of enjoying inflation-protecting financial technologies is directly related to the income level [30]. This effect can be clearly observed in Iran. Moreover, the portion of income saved in the form of cash assets to be used in unpredicted emergency situations varies, depending on the income level; individuals with higher income have to keep a larger portion of their income, which makes them more vulnerable to inflation corrosion. The increased inflation also enhances inequality by slowing down economic growth since fluctuations and uncertainty rise as inflation rises, and this reduces investment and consequently, economic growth. On the other hand, Romer [31] demonstrated that the poor were typically debtors and since the real values of nominal debts reduce as inflation increases, income was redistributed from creditors to debtors. However, as such debts are not very large (at least on average), the economic importance of this variation is slight. Empirical studies conducted in Iran suggest that inflation has worsened the distribution of income [2].
Considering the adverse impacts of income inequality on the economy of countries and the inflation of Iran, it is particularly important to investigate the impact of inflation on income inequality. To cope with inequitable distribution of income, it is required to identify factors influencing the inequitable distribution of income and make policies to improve the inequality at different levels and deciles of society based on their effects on the distribution of income [21]. Although the problem is important, and theoretical studies have been conducted on the relationship between inflation and income inequality, a small number of studies focused on the relationship between the two variables [16]. However, despite their considerable revenues, income inequalities in developing countries have led policy-makers and statesmen to employ appropriate economic policies in order to reduce income gaps and consequent social tensions [3]. Given the importance of income distribution and the considerable relationship between the optimal inflation rate and income inequality, by adopting the dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) approach, the present study determines the optimal inflation rate to minimize income inequality among households that distinctly keep their assets in the form of profitable assets and households that mainly keep cash [33].
The remainder of the study is organized as follows: Section 2 provides the theoretical foundations; Section 3 reviews the literature; Section 4 proposes hypotheses; Section 5 describes the proposed model; Section 6 provides the results; Section 7 concludes the work; and, Section 8 makes suggestions for future works.
2 Theoretical Foundations
Financial development improves economic growth. A number of empirical studies, such as Degrigorior and Gidoni indicated that financial development considerably reduced economic growth in the Latin American countries in the 1970s and 1980s. It should be noted that these countries had relatively large inflation rates in the two decades. This led the World Bank to issue a financial circular that recommended developing countries not to pursue financial reform unless their inflation rates had reduced sufficiently. Apparently, a large inflation rate was assumed to negatively impact the performance of financial markets and change the relationship between financial development and economic growth. In their empirical study, Boyd et al. [34] proved the inflation rate to be negatively related to the performance of financial markets. This probability was overlooked in many studies in theoretical literature.
The theoretical literature has described mechanisms in which even the predictable rise of inflation is inconsistent with the ability of the financial sector to efficiently allocate resources. Particularly, recent theories emphasized on the asymmetry of information in credit markets and indicated how an increased inflation rate positively influenced credit market friction and negatively impacted the performance of the financial sector and consequently, the long-term activities of the real part of the economy [35] .
A shared feature of these theories is that they consider a very endogenous type of information friction. Given this feature, a rise in the inflation rate of the real return rate generally diminishes not only money but also the entire assets. An implicit decline in the real return intensifies the friction of the credit market. Since such friction leads to credit rationing, credit rationing is intensified as much as inflation. As a result, the financial sector provides lower loans, resource allocation becomes less efficient, and the activities of financial intermediaries in investment reduce due to the negative consequents. A decline in the formation of capital negatively impacts long-term economic performance and activity of the stock market [35, 36].
Moore, Choi et al., and Azariadis and Smith emphasized that when inflation is high enough, since the returns of deposits reduce, it leads to the reduced deposits and reduced number of depositors, intensified information friction, and consequently, scarce financial credits. Moreover, Schreft and Huybens and Smith [36], and Huybens and Smith [35] proposed the idea that economies with high inflation rates will not reach or even become close to a stable condition in which their capital reserves are high. In addition, due to higher rates resulting from high inflation rates, such economies clearly offer less efficient financial markets. In the inflation situation, financial intermediation has become more difficult since the information flows of the real investment returns have become less certain and less available. This will lead to loaners mostly focusing on short-term objectives in their asset portfolios and limit their long-term loans. Eventually, a major portion of loans is directed toward loans that are most likely to be used to respond to operation costs. Inflation can also suppress financial intermediation by eroding the usefulness of monetary assets and impacting policy decisions that distort the financial structure [37]. According to Friedman’s Optimum Monetary Quantity Rule, resource allocation is performed completely and optimally in a monetary economy that is in a complete competition when the nominal productivity rate is zero. In this case, inflation-caused disturbance is minimized. Thus, the optimal inflation rate is the one at which the nominal productivity is zero. When the inflation rate exceeds the optimal level in an economy, the nominal interest rate exceeds zero. In this case, Pareto optimum allocation does not occur. As a result, the social welfare reduces, creating welfare costs. According to Friedman, the optimal social point is the one at which the final social benefit of maintaining the last currency is equal to the final cost of money from the social view. Since the cost of producing the last currency is zero for the community, the final social benefit of maintaining money, or the nominal interest rate, should be zero. Thus, in such a political system, the inflation rate will be equal to the negative quantity of the real interest rate. In fact, the optimal inflation rate is negative in Freidman’s rule (Sidrauski’s pattern is a suitable framework to calculate the optimal inflation rate in a steady state since when money is directly incorporated in the utility function, the lower maintenance level of money balances influences the welfare level as a result of the higher inflation rate. The optimal inflation is obtained when the minimum loss has been imposed on the social welfare function [6]). [38]
2.1 Distribution of Income
Sahot [49] divided income distribution theories into the ability theory, stochastic theory, individual choice theory, human capital theory, theories of educational inequalities, inheritance theory, lifecycle theory, public income redistribution theories, more complete theories, and theories of distributive justice. Kaasa suggested that these factors can be divided into five groups, including economic growth and development, demographic factors, political factors, historical, cultural, and natural factors, and macroeconomic factors. According to the literature, inflation is a factor affecting inflation income inequality. However, the effect of inflation on income inequality is not theoretically known.
2.2 Impact of Inflation on Income Inequality
The real values of nominal debts decline as the inflation rate rises. Thus, income is redistributed from creditors to debtors. In other words, debtors benefit from inflation since they pay debts whose purchasing power has declined. Since the poor are usually debtors on average, the rise of inflation through this channel benefits them on average and reduces inequality. However, Romer and Romer [31] emphasized that although the poor are debtors, this effect’s economic significance may be slight since such debts are not significant [41].
Additionally, the Philips curve assumes an inverse relationship between unemployment and inflation, i.e., a high inflation level reduces unemployment. Given that unemployment is one of the most important factors influencing the level of poverty in society. A rise in inflation can contribute to improving income distribution and reducing poverty by decreasing unemployment [26].
If nominal wages remain unchanged, the real income declines as inflation rises, and those with fixed income, who cannot change their income in proportion to price rises (e.g., governmental employees, workers, whose wages are not based on inflation) undergo losses, with reduced purchasing power. This effect is not the same for everyone since some individuals, particularly those with high income, may receive no fixed income, with their nominal income rising as inflation rises, while the nominal income of the low-income class remains unchanged. Therefore, income inequality rises through this channel as inflation rises. Reviewing the results of Shiller and Easterly and Fisher indicates the importance of this effect in practice [41].
The abilities of different classes for compensating for the inflation-reduced purchasing power are different. Typically, wealthy classes are abler to protect themselves from inflation-induced shocks. Such individuals typically invest in a portfolio of different assets, covering the effects of inflation. This, however, is not easy for low-income classes since they require a minimum level of assets to engage in such activities, but they cannot provide it. Thus, the poor keep a larger portion of their assets in cash than the rich, which exposes them to inflation-reduced purchasing power more than the rich. Therefore, an increase in inflation increases inequality by decreasing the real values of monetary assets [16]. Inflation reduces the real values of governmental transfer payments, such as cash subsidies and unemployment insurance payments. Since transfer payment receivers are typically among the poorest classes of the population, inflation reduces inequality if such payments are not adjusted by inflation [48]. A decline in inflation can improve long-term growth by bringing stability in macroeconomics and motivating investment. Although the relationship between income and growth is not known empirically and theoretically, stable long-term growth is expected to reduce income inequality. Thus, inequality is predicted to rise due to reduced long-term growth as inflation rises; however, the positive effect of reduced inflation is the case only in countries with high initial inflation (typically hyperinflation). In economies with medium or low inflation, inflation is less likely to create a degree of macroeconomic instability to reduce investment and thus, long-term growth. Fig. 1 demonstrates a summary of the channels and negative and positive (dual) effects of (predicted) long-term inflation in income inequality.
Fig. 1: The dual effects of long-term inflation on income inequality [48]
Considering the above-mentioned, the net effect of inflation on income inequality seems to be ambiguous in the long term. In this respect, Galli [48] believed that the net effect of inflation on income inequality in the long term depends on the initial inflation rate. When the inflation rate is high, a reduction in the inflation rate can reduce income inequality through its positive effects. On the other hand, when the inflation rate is low, the distribution benefits of inflation may be small, while inflation and unemployment are more likely to encounter, which would worsen income inequality [41]. Additionally, a high inflation rate influences the decisions of production and financial institutions. It encourages economic agents to attempt to obtain inflation-induced rents rather than attempting to raise their income by raising their institutions’ productivity. Capital profitability arising from inflation adversely impacts not only the behavior of economic agents but only the inter-time allocation of resources. When there are monopoly and influence centers along with inflation, the profitability of unproductive activities and rent-seeking activities increases. Thus, resources are allocated to activities that provide significant profits to specific individuals rather than they are allocated to job-creating activities that can play an essential role in income distribution improvement. This worsens income distribution [22]. Fig. 2 illustrates how inflation impacts inequality by enhancing rent activities.
Fig. 2: The impact of inflation on inequality by enhancing rent activities [22]
Scholtz proposed another relationship route between inflation and inequality. They concluded that when product prices change in response to changed production factor prices and wages (i.e., pressure-cost inflation), a change in prices can reduce the contribution of interests to income inequality. However, when demand for the final product changes the price level (i.e., pressure-demand inflation), and wages are determined on nominal bases, the contribution of profits increases in the same direction as price changes, which increases income inequality. This is related to the Philips curve. According to A.W. Philips, a rise in demand reduces the unemployment rate but increases the wage growth rate and inflation rate. Then, as money illusion declines, the unemployment rate and inflation rate rise. Fig. 3 represents the impact of demand pressure-induced inflation on income inequality.
Fig. 3: The impact of demand pressure-induced inflation on income inequality
3 Literature Review
Different studies have investigated the determination of the optimal inflation rate and the effects of a change in the optimal inflation in macroeconomic variables. Some studies incorporated the minimization of welfare costs, while some others included the minimization of income inequality. Table 1 provides Iranian studies, while Table 2 represents non-Iranian studies.
Table 1: Iranian studies
Authors | Year | Model | Results |
Farahmandmanesh and Armanmehr [20] | 2018 | The linear expense system and the Atkinson index | A dramatic rise in prices (high inflation) increases inequality. Also, among the influencing factors, inflation has the largest impact on the creation of income inequality (~48%) |
Golkhandan [23] | 2016 | Smooth transition regression (STR) model | Inflation non-linearly influences income inequality in the long term. The inflation rate affects income inequality in the form of a dual-regime structure in which one regime has negative effects, while the other one has positive effects. |
Jalali [11] | 2016 | Atkinson welfare function | The findings indicated that poor classes suffered from inflation pressure more than non-poor classes before 2011. The results were not the case for the period after 2011. |
Mirbagheri Hayyer and Shokuhifard [25] | 2016 | Panel data | A rise in inflation diminished purchasing power and increased Gini coefficient and inequality in Islamic countries |
Table 1: continue | |||
Bakhshi Dastjerdi and Sheykh Ansari [6] | 2015 | Code optimization | The inflation rate that can provide the maximum social welfare to the economy of Iran was found to be 1.96%. |
Eslami [1] | 2014 | Cointegration method | A rise in the domestic per capita gross production and inflation rate enhances the income gap in society, and a rise in per capita subsidy, per capita employment, and per capita wealth tax decreases the income gap. |
Hadian and Izadi[39] | 2014 | Threshold regression | The optimal inflation rate of the economy of Iran was found to be 5.5%. |
Komeyjani and Mohammadzadeh [21] | 2014 | Apparently-unordered regression | Inflation, unemployment, government expenses, and the ratio of 10% high-income class to 10% poor negatively impact inequality, and a rise in the subsidies of basic goods and the contribution of 40% poor improves inequality. The results indicated that a rise in inflation, unemployment, basic goods subsidies, and the ratio of 10% wealthy to 10% poor benefits high-income classes, leading to enhanced inequality. Also, a rise in the contribution of 40% poor benefits low-income classes, leading to reduced inequality. |
Shakeri et al. [165] | 2013 | The Toda and Yamamoto approach | There is a nonlinear relationship between inflation and income inequality in Iran. |
Zaeri and Nadri [13] | 2013 | Bailey's partial-equilibrium model | The mean inflation welfare cost and nominal interest rate were estimated to be 3.54 and 1.42, respectively. |
Ebadatian et al. [18] | 2012 | Bailey’s surplus welfare criterion and Lucas’s compensating variation | The optimal inflation rate was obtained to be 1% and 3% by Bailey’s and Lucas’s methods at the highest inequality avoidance level in Iran, respectively. |
Nazari and Mazaheri [26] | 2011 | Vector autoregression | The hypothesis of a U-shaped relationship between inflation and income distribution was not supported. |
Tashkini and Afzali [7] | 2011 | SVAR method | Housing is a stable component of inflation in the economy of Iran, and it is consistent with expectations. Also, the momentums of basic inflation, import price, and non-basic inflation explained 40% and 6% of inflation variance, respectively. |
Kafaei and Moradbeigi [28] | 2010 | Descriptive analysis and wealth-oriented gap | The findings revealed an inflation inequality between rural and urban regions in time periods. Inequality fluctuated over time. However, it was higher in urban regions than in rural regions. In addition, inequality has increased in recent years, making it necessary to put in place specific policies for different regions, including rural and urban regions, and for provinces. |
Abounouri et al. [3] | 2010 | Ordinary most squares | Inflation and unemployment pose larger impacts on Gini coefficient urban regions than in rural regions in Iran. |
Hadizonouz [24] | 2010 | Analytical | The government should apply the required structural reforms in its structure in order to make and execute policies for economic growth and social justice |
Zibaei [14] | 2005 | Linear regreion | An increase in inflation and unemployment not only does not improve income distribution but also functions as a descending tax that worsens income distribution. |
Abounouri [2] | 1997 | Iteratively reweighted least squares | A 1% rise in the inflation rate brought a 6% increase in the expense inequalities of households in the next period. |
Asgari [19] | 1991 | Simple dual-variate regression | The results indicated the negative impact of inflation on the maximum income gap, while no significant relationship was observed between inflation and the Gini coefficient. Also, an inverse significant relationship was found between inflation and the contribution of 10% poor class. |
Table 2: Non-Iranian studies
Authors | Year | Model | Results |
Deyshappriya [40] | 2016 | Panel data analysis | It was recommended to maintain price stability for keeping income distribution with higher income and low income inequality. |
Menna and Tirell [30] | 2016 | Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) | When the contribution of limited factors was measured for adaptation to Gini index in USA, the satisfactory inflation rate was obtained to be above 4%. |
Monnin[41] | 2014 | Panel data analysis | There was a U-shaped relationship between inflation and income inequality in OECD countries; a rise in inflation to 13.3% reduced income inequality. At inflation rates above 13.3%, a rise in the inflation rate increased income inequality. |
Thalassinos et al. [42] | 2015 | Panel data analysis | Inflation had a positive and significant effect on income inequality in European countries. |
Hitoshi et al.[43] | 2008 | DSGE | The optimal inflation rate was estimated to be 0.5-2.0% in different cases. This range varies, depending on assumptions and parameters. |
Amornthum | 2004 | Threshold regression | Adding the second-order term of filtered inflation to the model not only increased the model’s significance but also created a U-shaped relationship between inflation and income inequality in the studied countries. |
Bulir[44] | 2001 | Panel data analysis | Inflation nonlinearly impacted inequality. |
Galli et al. [48] | 2001 | Panel data analysis | There was a U-shaped relationship between inflation and inequality. The minimum estimated inequality was obtained to be 6% and 12% for the USA and OECD countries, respectively. |
Parker[47] | 1998 | Multivariate regression | Inflation increases income inequality if fixed wages such as pension payments are not adjusted in proportion to inflation. |
Bulir[45] | 1998 | Kuznets Model | A rapid reduction in inflation created a significantly lower income distribution inequality. Also, it was found that a further decrease in inflation to very low levels increased inequality. |
Bulir and Gulde[46] | 1995 | Extended model | The results supported the Kuznets hypothesis and the destructive impact of increased inflation, changes in inflation, and changes in the nominal exchange rate on income distribution. |
4 Hypotheses
Based on Hitoshi et al. [43] and theoretical foundations, the following hypotheses were made:
Hypothesis 1: The optimal inflation rate can be measured by the dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) model
Hypothesis 2: A reduction in the inflation rate to below the optimal inflation rate while other factors are fixed increases income inequality
Hypothesis 3: A rise in the inflation rate while other factors are fixed increases income inequality
Hypothesis 4: Income inequality is minimized at the optimal inflation rate
5 Methodology and Model
This study employs DSGE models due to their particular advantages. Such models offer various advantages, which makes them interesting and beneficial for analyzing macroeconomic policies. The DSGE structure is one of such advantages, i.e., each equation has an economic interpretation in the model. In addition, such models have microeconomic bases and are extracted by optimizing the behavior of households and institutions in the economy. As another feature of DSGE models, they are stochastic. Thus, they consider the fact that the economy is influenced by stochastic shocks, analyzing the impacts of such shocks on the economy. Such features have made DSGE models of interest and effectiveness for analyzing different macroeconomic policies’ impacts.
5.1 Shocks in the Model
In the proposed model, the general relationships between the main components, including households, institutions, the government, the central bank, and the external world, are explained. Then, details are provided in proportion to the relationships’ types. The Model’s shocks include
A. Supply-side shocks (workforce productivity),
B. Demand-side shocks (investment preferences and government expenses) (Government demand G, as a component of the total demand, causes demand-side shocks), and
C. Money shocks (the interest rate and other targeted variables). Money shocks typically follow a first-order autoregression process.
Once the DSGE models are specified, two important conditions should be met for equilibrium: 1) brokers should perform optimization, and 2) markets, including the goods market and work market, should be cleared. Fig. 4 shows the shocks included in the model [17].
Fig. 4: The DSGE model’s shocks [50]
Households are consumers and make decisions between consumption and investment. Workforce supply is performed only by this component. The income of households comes from three sections, including workforce supply, intermediary goods production institutions’ profits, and receiving government transfer payments. They maximize the current value of their expected utility. Finally, their expenses are purchasing final goods and services and paying taxes to the government.
5.2 Specifying the DSGE model for the economy of Iranian
A) Household
In the proposed economy, population and households with unlimited horizons are assumed to be present. Moreover, consumed purchases are assumed to the same as the total costs of transactions.
| (1) |
| (2) |
U= | (3) |
max s.t.
| (4) |
| (5) |
| (6) |
| (7) |
| (8) |
| (9) |
| (10) |
| (11) |
=
| (12) |
1-[
| (13) |
| (14) |
| (15) |
| (16) |
| (17) |
| (18) |
| (19) |
| (20) |
s.t.
| (21) |
|
|
|
(22) |
| (23) |
| (24) |
| (25) |
| (26) |
| (27) |
| (28) |
and
| (29) |
| (30) |
Related articles
-
Presenting a model of tax non-compliance in Iran based on the network analysis Process (ANP)
Print Date : 2023-05-01 -
Political Connections and Related-Party Transactions: Evidence from Iranian Firms
Print Date : 2020-07-01 -
-
Study of Financial Distress Spillover Effect among Automobile Supply Chain Companies
Print Date : 2022-01-01
The rights to this website are owned by the Raimag Press Management System.
Copyright © 2021-2024